Reconciling A Hayekian/organic Approach With “Designing” Markets

Lynne Kiesling

In the comments to my carbon market post from Friday, D. F. Linton asks this very good question:

How does one invoke Hayek in one breath and the speak of “designing” a market in the next while keeping a straight face?

Good question, and one I struggle with every day as an economist who works on regulation in retail markets and comes from a very organic/complexity/ dynamism perspective. D. F. Linton’s question lurks in my mind constantly. At a practical level, I reconcile them by acknowledging that when we are dealing with markets or industries that have historically had a significant amount of regulation and government control and involvement, the movement from heavily regulated to thriving market processes is very unlikely to be organic. It’s also unlikely to be a healthy transition, because embedded regulation creates embedded special interests who would like to see the regulation persist and will resist change, so if the transition process is too “laissez-faire”, the embedded special interests are likely to succeed at manipulating the transition to their advantage. For evidence on this point I give you post-Soviet Russia.

So in regulated industries like electricity, I think that’s one of the big challenges: how do you get to the situation in which market processes are organic, given that you are not starting from an atomistic, almost-clean-slate beginning? How do you get to the organic market processes when you are starting with historic incumbents (and regulators) that are themselves creatures of the regulatory process? Coming up with market rules that do not favor those incumbents over potential entrants is what I mean by “designing markets” as alluded to above.

The carbon situation is a bit different, because it’s an introduction of regulation, not a removal of regulation in response to dynamic technological and economic change. Here my inner Hayekian teams up with my inner Demsetzian, if you will, to ask “compared to what?”: if such regulation is going to be implemented, and if we can do it in a way that increases total surplus by defining property rights and allowing private parties to trade those rights, how does that arrangement perform relative to other realistic, feasible alternatives to such a policy? That’s the spirit in which I intended the initial post.

But the truly Hayekian sense in which I can reconcile the organic/complexity approach with “designing markets” is the sense in which Hayek writes in Law, Legislation, and Liberty. Market processes for the mutually beneficial, voluntary exchange of rights always occur within a context of law, of legal institutions, whether formal or informal or a combination of both. Many of what we think of as the most free and most capitalist of our market institutions, such as financial exchanges, involve elaborate contracts and laws enforcing those contracts. This legal context determines the rules by which we exchange; the context and the rules form the market institution. The quality of that institution and its variation across places or across time can affect how much exchange actually occurs, and how much net benefit is created through exchange. Even in free markets, the market institution is carefully designed, although in most organic markets the design process is a very distributed one, building upon centuries of legal precedent and experience, so it doesn’t look like it’s highly designed or deliberate.

The problem is that in markets coming out of regulation or in markets that have never existed before, the market institution has to be designed in less-than-organic circumstances. That’s the hard part, because it introduces a political dimension to the design of market institutions that is not present in more organic situations, because there are special interests in the status quo and special interests in the future setup, all trying to influence the design of the rules in the market institution.

I hope that clarifies how I can reconcile them. Another lens through which you can think about it is imperfection. In a perfect world there should be no need to reconcile Hayekian and organic perspectives with deliberate design, because there would be no transaction costs and everything would be fluid and self-organizing. Reality is not so perfect, so I think we have to be willing to recognize the situations in which some deliberate organization is necessary to get us to a point where we have institutions that can support self-organization.

4 thoughts on “Reconciling A Hayekian/organic Approach With “Designing” Markets”

  1. I liked Linton’s question and I liked Lynne’s answer, too, but I had a slightly different reaction.

    It turned out that my comment was getting too long, so I’m exercising my prerogative as an author here and will post it separately.

  2. I, the moderate Republican, used to have a hiking buddy who was a moderate Democrat. The amusing thing was that we’d often start discussions from totally different moral or philosophical perspectives, but then 3 miles later, agree what was likely to work well in practice.

    I think some good balance has been established in this country, going back a hundred years. We chose to create public monopolies in some (very few) things, but not others. Those thing work very well, in practice.

    I guess my worry is that an ideological drive to remove the last few examples … might be just that, and less based on reason, or moderation. It might be a case of going beyond what’s broken, to fixing what ain’t.

    And … queue recent studies on brain structure, neuroscience, etc. … I’d wonder if the people asking for major changes (on the right or left) aren’t themselves “outliers” in the population. The last caveat to think about here is, if human beings have a distribution of natures, we need a solution that works for that distribution … and not just for a more uniform subset.

  3. I, the moderate Republican, used to have a hiking buddy who was a moderate Democrat. The amusing thing was that we’d often start discussions from totally different moral or philosophical perspectives, but then 3 miles later, agree what was likely to work well in practice.

    I think some good balance has been established in this country, going back a hundred years. We chose to create public monopolies in some (very few) things, but not others. Those thing work very well, in practice.

    I guess my worry is that an ideological drive to remove the last few examples … might be just that, and less based on reason, or moderation. It might be a case of going beyond what’s broken, to fixing what ain’t.

    And … queue recent studies on brain structure, neuroscience, etc. … I’d wonder if the people asking for major changes (on the right or left) aren’t themselves “outliers” in the population. The last caveat to think about here is, if human beings have a distribution of natures, we need a solution that works for that distribution … and not just for a more uniform subset.

  4. There is no contradiction between Hayek’s negative views on central planning (by direction) and the eternal task of improving the legal, political and moral framework of the market order. One of the problems that you flagged is the question of how much to try to achieve at a stroke. Roger Douglas, the great deregulator in New Zealand, moved on a broad front, partly to hasten the gains, and partly because he figured that mostly the same people would be in the street protesting all of the (say) ten major reforms and if he did them one at a time the volume of opposition would be over-estimated by a factor approaching ten. He had the advantage of working in a national government without the complication of states.

    For learning purposes it helps to do things one at a time so the results are easier to assess.

Comments are closed.